Table of contents
Articles
"Convex preferences": a new definition
Michael Richter and Ariel Rubinstein |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW 1169–1183 |
Justifying optimal play via consistency
Florian Brandl and Felix Brandt |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW 1185–1201 |
Robustness of full revelation in multisender cheap talk
Margaret Meyer, Inés Moreno de Barreda, and Julia Nafziger |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW 1203–1236 |
Common enrollment in school choice
Mehmet Ekmekci and M. Bumin Yenmez |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW 1237–1270 |
On the clock of the combinatorial clock auction
Maarten Janssen and Bernhard Kasberger |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW 1271–1308 |
School choice under partial fairness
Umut Dur, A. Arda Gitmez, and Özgür Yılmaz |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW 1309–1346 |
Best experienced payoff dynamics and cooperation in the Centipede game
William H. Sandholm, Segismundo S. Izquierdo, and Luis R. Izquierdo |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW Supplementary Appendix 1347–1386 |
Enforcing social norms: Trust-building and community enforcement
Joyee Deb and Julio Gonzalez-Diaz |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW Supplementary Appendix 1387–1434 |
Optimal dynamic contracting: the first-order approach and beyond
Marco Battaglini and Rohit Lamba |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW Supplementary Appendix 1435–1482 |
Gridlock and inefficient policy instruments
David Austen-Smith, Wioletta Dziuda, Bård Harstad, and Antoine Loeper |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW 1483–1534 |
Full substitutability
John William Hatfield, Scott Duke Kominers, Alexandru Nichifor, Michael Ostrovsky, and Alexander Westkamp |
Abstract
PRINT VIEW 1535–1590 |